Business appraisal standards grew directly out of real estate appraisal standards…specifically, commercial real estate appraisal standards. These commercial real estate appraisal standards include three generally accepted approaches to valuing commercial real estate: (1) Asset (Cost) Approach, (2) Income Approach, and (3) Market Approach. And in most appraisals, it comes down to the Income Approach vs Market Approach.
The Income Approach is useful in valuing commercial real estate when market comparable sales are difficult to find because this approach corresponds to the way in which market participants (investors) value commercial real estate. Future earnings are estimated and then discounted to the present using a discount or capitalization rate.
Historically, market comparable sales were difficult to find for operating businesses, hence the reliance on the Income Approach. Today, however, market data is far more readily available.
Additionally, using the Income Approach to value operating businesses is fundamentally different than using it for valuing commercial real estate. There are two key ingredients in the Income Approach: (1) predicting future earnings, and (2) using an appropriate discount or capitalization rate. These are much more difficult to accurately estimate for privately-held businesses.
Predicting future earnings for commercial real estate is relatively straightforward. The property has a history of tenancy rental and occupancy rates from which to model the future. Existing leases have rent escalators, and historic market increases provide a good guideline for predicting the future. Predicting five years out is, if not perfect, generally reasonably reliable within an acceptable range.
On the other hand, predicting future earnings for operating businesses five years out into the future (the typical timeframe used) is highly subjective, if not outright speculative. The future financial performances of small and mid-sized businesses are typically far more volatile, unpredictable, and unknown than commercial buildings (as well as, royalty agreements, other financial instruments). The further out into the future one goes, the more uncertain the projection.
For example, let’s assume a company, Acme Enterprises, is being valued by two different appraisers using a popular type of Income Approach called the Discounted Cash Flow method, using Free Cash Flow (FCF) as the measure of earnings. Acme’s FCF for five years is as follows:
Because of the volatility in FCF, it is difficult to arrive at a growth rate that would be viewed as completely objective. For example, in the last year (2014) FCF was down $50,000, but the trend over 5 years is up. Do you take the compound annual growth rate over the past 4 years? Or do you weight the more recent years more? Ten different appraisers would probably come up with ten different growth rates.
Let us consider a scenario where two well-meaning appraisers value the same business. We will call it Acme Enterprises.
Appraiser #1 takes the 4-year compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of 9.2%, while Appraiser #2 is more conservative, giving more weight to the most recent down year, and uses a rate of 5.0%. Below are the 5-year Free Cash Flow (FCF) projections by both appraisers:
The full DCF method includes an estimate of terminal value, and a discount rate to arrive at present value. Using a terminal value multiple of 5, and a discount rate of 20%, the results are as follows:
As one can see, the seemingly small difference in growth rates is magnified over time. In this case, when a terminal value is applied to the final year (year 5) of FCF, and the present value is calculated, the difference is approximately $1,280,000 (a 16% variance), even when using the same discount rate and terminal value multiple.
The second problem with the Income Approach is the formulation of the discount rate (or capitalization rate). Unlike the rates used for commercial properties, which usually fall into a fairly narrow range based on the type of property, rates used for valuing privately-held businesses vary widely. The reason for this rests in how the rates are calculated. While rates for commercial properties are calculated using market data for similar properties in the area, the methods for calculating the rates for privately-held business enterprises begin with very dissimilar comparable information.
Specifically, the journey to private company discount rates/capitalization rates begins with the use of public company data (i.e. stock market data). Then very subjective measures are used to convert the public company rate into a private company rate (usually for a much smaller privately-held subject company). These adjustments for size and liquidity are very subjective, and therefore, 10 experienced appraisers, even using the same public company data, will almost invariably arrive at 10 different rates. The consequences of these differences can be quite significant in the final conclusion of value.
Using the same example from earlier, even if the appraisers had used the same growth rate of 9.2%, but used slightly different discount rates based on subjective differences, the results would be substantially different, as seen below.
A small difference of only 3.0% in the discount rates selected (somewhat subjectively) by the appraisers has a large difference of approximately $830,000 (a 10% variance) in the separate conclusions of value, even when using the same growth rate and terminal value multiple.
When using the differing growth rates of 9.2% and 5.0% from the previous example, the differences in the conclusions of value are even starker.
The combination of the two small variances in the assumptions by the different appraisers creates a value spread of approximately $1,980,000 (a 27% variance) in the separate conclusions of value, even when using the same terminal value multiple.
Despite the DCF Method being classified as an income approach, the terminal value is traditionally estimated by considering market-based multiples procured directly or indirectly from market participants. As such, the level of earnings and earnings growth rate play a significant role in estimating a terminal value multiple.
In this case, it is reasonable to assume that a company with estimated Year 5 FCF of approximately $2,100,000 and a growth rate of 9.2%, would deserve and receive a higher multiple than one with less FCF and a lower growth rate (approx. $1,700,000 and 5.0%, respectively). In the table below, a 0.5 difference in the terminal value multiple is introduced (5.0 vs. 5.5) to account for this assumption.
The small 0.5 difference in the terminal value multiple results in an additional difference in value of approximately $420,000 ($2,400,404 – $1,979,182). The total difference of $2,400,404 represents a variance of 33% in estimated market value.
This substantial difference of 33% in the conclusion of value is the result of very modest (and reasonable) differences in the assumptions made by the two hypothetical appraisers. Yet, this result, as poor as it is, represents perhaps the best possible outcome using the Income Approach. More varied assumptions and/or the use of the Gordon Growth Model for Terminal Value produce even more disparate conclusions of value.
A variant of the traditional DCF method is the DCF-GGM method. This model replaces the terminal value multiple with the Gordon Growth Model to calculate terminal value. The Gordon Growth Model is as follows:
Using the Gordon Growth Model Terminal Value, the results are as follows:
Since the terminal value in the DCF-GGM method is directly affected by the growth and discount rates, this method produces an even wider disparity than the traditional DCF model….a market value variance of 73%.
As demonstrated, even under the best circumstances, with experienced appraisers, the subjectivity of the inputs, and nature of the calculations can result in wildly disparate results. Because of these fundamental flaws, virtually no market participants in the small business market, and few market participants in the lower middle market are using the DCF Method as their primary method to value companies.
The same can be said for other methods under the Income Approach, which also lack market validity or widespread adoption, and are generally considered inferior to the DCF method. In other words, the Income Approach is a deeply flawed approach, and should not be used to estimate market value for privately-held operating businesses. The Market Approach is a much more reliable approach to appraising businesses.
by Rob Slee.
Business appraisers spend a considerable amount of time and energy using public securities information to derive private business values. This is understandable since Revenue Ruling 59-60 gives justification to considering the “market prices of…stocks actively traded…either on an exchange or over the counter” as one of eight factors to consider when valuing privately held businesses. Comparing public and private securities has created the need for elaborate economic bridges that enable appraisers to value private business interests vis-à-vis public data with ever more certainty. There is a problem with this methodology: it assumes that public and private capital markets are substitutes. This paper shows otherwise.
A number of factors separate the public and private markets, including:
The differences between public and private markets will be examined at several levels. First, the principle of substitution is used to determine if the markets are indeed substitutes. Next, the appropriateness of employing one capital market theory to explain the behavior of all parties within the various markets is discussed. Third, the structure of the public and private capital markets is analyzed. Finally, investor return expectations for each market are described. It is the premise of this paper that capital markets are differentiated by nearly every meaningful measure, and that solutions to problems within each market are found within that market.
The principle of substitution is a foundational concept underlying all appraisals of economic value. According to the principle of substitution value is determined by the cost of acquiring an equally desirable substitute. In other words, no one would knowingly pay more for something than it would cost to obtain an equally desirable substitute. Guideline transactions are used to define the market for businesses that are equally desirable substitutes for the subject business. It is important to recognize that the principle of substitution does not call for “identical” businesses as substitutes for the subject company. Instead, it calls for investments whose desirability is equal to that of the subject business. From an investment viewpoint guideline transaction prices are relevant to the value of private businesses when they are similar with respect to the degree of risk, the liquidity of the investment, and the involvement of management.1
An investment in a private company is typically riskier than an investment in a public company. Even within public companies, stocks of smaller companies are riskier than larger company stocks. Because of this, small company stocks command a higher expected rate of return in the market. Several companies study the relationship between risk and return in the public markets. The leading company, Ibbotson Associates, quantifies this relationship by publishing an annual study called the SBBI Yearbook. Relative to size, the Ibbotson studies indicate a higher equity risk premium for smaller common public stocks.An investment in a private company is typically riskier than an investment in a public company. Even within public companies, stocks of smaller companies are riskier than larger company stocks. Because of this, small company stocks command a higher expected rate of return in the market. Several companies study the relationship between risk and return in the public markets. The leading company, Ibbotson Associates, quantifies this relationship by publishing an annual study called the SBBI Yearbook. Relative to size, the Ibbotson studies indicate a higher equity risk premium for smaller common public stocks.2
Exhibit 1: Equity Risk Premiums
Average Sales | Equity Risk Premium |
$33 billion | 6.4% |
$753 million | 9.0% |
$47 million | 13.6% |
Equity risk premiums vary according to company size, as measured by sales volume. This means investors in smaller public companies actually have received greater returns to compensate for additional. As the leading valuation expert Shannon Pratt further indicates, the total risk, or standard deviation of annual returns, also increases with decreasing size.3 This implies the market does not ignore unsystematic risk (diversifiable risk), and requires extra returns for accepting that risk. Unsystematic risk is a function of characteristics of the company’s industry, the company itself, or the specific investment that is offered by the company. Examples of this diversifiable risk include management’s ability to step up to a challenge, the debt level of the company, and any other factors that are company specific. This extra return required by the market is called the size premium.
The size premium, which is also studied by Ibbotson Associates, measures the amount of return in addition to the basic equity risk premium noted above. Ibbotson’s small company category is called Micro-cap equity size premia. It is the measurement of returns in excess of those predicted for the portfolio of stocks represented by the smallest 20 percent of stocks on the NYSE, American Stock Exchange, and Nasdaq National Market, with current capitalization below $192 million. The size premium for the years 1996-2000 ranged from 2.5% to 3.4%.4
Using the Ibbotson data, smaller public stocks are considered riskier than larger public stocks. Investors in small public stocks require a greater return to compensate them for this additional risk. The return difference is substantial. When considering the equity risk and size premium together, there is roughly a 10% return difference between large and small public companies.
If a risk difference exists between public companies of different sizes, it follows that expected returns are greater for smaller private companies as compared to smaller public companies. Part of this added risk is explained by unsystematic risk associated with private ownership. Since private owners cannot diversify their holdings nearly to the extent public shareholders can, an extra return, beyond the equity risk and size premiums, is needed to estimate an appropriate expected rate of return. This additional risk associated with private companies is sometimes referred to as specific company risk. Estimating specific company risk generally requires a judgment call by the appraiser.
The prevalent method for determining private discount rates, or private expected rates of return, starts with required return rates for public company, then adds layers of risk. Ultimately a judgment is necessary on the private company’s additional specific risk, as it relates to the public guideline company’s expected rates of return. Using the principal of substitution, it makes more sense to determine the private expected rates of return for similar investments.
Two Types of Risk |
Equity Risk Premium The risk associated with systematic risk, which is also called non-diversifiable risk. Investors are compensated for taking this equity risk by receiving a premium over the risk free rate (called the equity risk premium). |
Size Premium The risk associated with unsystematic risk, or diversifiable risk. This risk is company specific, and investors require an extra return for accepting it (called the size premium). |
The second tenet of the principle of substitution, in terms of the relevancy of using public guideline information to value private business interests, involves the liquidity of the investment. Private companies do not have a ready market for their shares and thus are highly illiquid investments. The Emory studies show that even companies in the process of going public suffer major discounts due to illiquidity.5 In the studies, Emory analyzed over 2,200 offerings to determine the relationship between (1) the price at which the stock was initially offered to the public and (2) the price at which the latest private transactions occurred up to five months prior to the initial public offering. Emory eliminated companies with operating losses and those with no transactions in the five months prior to the IPO. The mean price difference for qualifying transactions was 44%. Thus, companies that were moving towards becoming public suffered, on the average, a 44% loss of value due to illiquidity. Other studies verify the Emory results.6
Using liquidity of the investment as a comparison, public and private stocks are not substitutes for each other.
The final test as to whether public and private stocks are good substitutes is the degree to which management is involved. If management of a public and private company acts similarly and is driven by similar motives, then there is reason to believe the end result of their efforts would be similar. Clearly, there are differences in how public and private companies are managed. Exhibit 2 describes a number of differences in manager involvement.
Exhibit 2: Differences in Manager Involvement
Public | Private |
Profit Maximization | Personal Wealth Creation |
Not Driven by Taxes | Consumed with Limiting Taxes |
Functionally Organized | Owner Wears Many Hats |
Customer Contact from Below | Customer Contact from the Top |
Personal Time vs. Business Time | Only 24 Hours in a Day |
Public managers are driven to maximize profits with a side concern for decreasing corporate income taxes. Private owner-managers are driven to increase the cash available to increase their personal wealth with direct and specific objectives to limit all taxes. Public managers organize their companies functionally; whereas, private owner-managers tend to wear many functional hats themselves and organize their companies around customer needs. For instance, rather than have customers contact sales or marketing representatives directly as they do in public companies, many private companies have customers contact the owner-manager directly, who then involves the appropriate personnel. Finally, professional managers build a wall between personal and business time. With all of their wealth standing behind the business, owner-managers are on the job twenty-four hours per day, seven days a week. Therefore, there are substantial managerial differences between public and private managers.
The issue of using public stock information as a relevant source for valuing private stocks can be viewed by analogy. Most private companies have different foundations, both financially and organizationally, from those of most public companies. Perhaps a comparison can be found between two different industrial buildings. Assume both contain 100,000 sq. ft. on five acres of land. Both are zoned the same, with approximately the same internal layout and capabilities. The only difference is that one sits on a shaky foundation, and the other sits on bedrock. As long as their foundations are disregarded, they are equally desirable substitutes. But few would ignore such foundational consideration.
The foregoing discussion regarding the principle of substitution suggests that public guideline transaction prices are not relevant to the valuation of private business interests. All three areas, risk, liquidity and management involvement, point to major differences between public and private company stocks. Under this analysis, public stocks are generally not good substitutes or comparisons for private stocks.
Until recently, private market players had only corporate finance theories to explain the behavior of the private capital markets. They were left to assume that corporate finance theories explain and predict actions in the private markets. A recent book demonstrates otherwise.7 Corporate finance theories explain and organize the public capital markets but have never been intended to explain nonpublic capital markets. Private markets must be explained using theories tailored to experience in those markets. Employing powerful theories in the wrong context leads to frustration and a loss of utility. For example, assessing risk using a theoretical structure applicable to one market while expecting a return in another market causes a serious disconnect.
At least three capital markets theories are needed to explain the broader capital markets. Exhibit 3 shows the linkage between each market and theory.
Exhibit 3: Capital Markets and Theories
Small company markets theory does not yet exist in the literature. Elements of this emerging theory are extant, such as valuation standards for appraising small business interests, capital raising constructs such as the use of the Small Business Administration’s programs, and various articles and writings on transferring small businesses. At some point in the near future, institutions within the small business market will sufficiently mature enabling a holistic theory to develop.
Private capital markets theory is the integrated capital market theory unique to private companies, especially those with annual sales of $5 million to $500 million. This theory describes the valuation, capitalization and transfer of private business interests. These three interrelated areas rely on each other in a triangular fashion. This interrelation not only provides strength to market architecture, but it also requires users of the body of knowledge to understand all three legs of the triangle. Just understanding valuation or capital structure or transfer will not get the job done in the marketplace. Recognizing the triangle acknowledges what the private companies need most – holistic solutions. Typically a private business owner is faced with a financial problem that can only be solved by drawing information from throughout the body of capital knowledge.
Finally, corporate finance theory was developed in the 1960’s to explain the behavior of large companies in the public capital markets. These theories include: capital asset pricing theory, efficient market theory, option pricing theory, agency theory, net present value, portfolio theory, and others.
Theories are useful only if they are predictive. Corporate finance theory does not predict behavior in the private capital markets; likewise, private capital markets theory is not predictive of the public markets. The starkness of this contrast is shown by the assumptions behind corporate finance theory and private capital markets theory.
Exhibit 4: Assumptions Behind Corporate Finance Theory and Private Capital Markets Theory
Corporate Finance Theory | Private Capital Markets Theory |
Use of a C-Corporation | Can be any type entity (S-Corp., LLC, etc.) |
Value is established by a market | Value is established at a point in time |
Ready access to public capital markets | No access to public capital markets |
Owners have limited liability | Owners have unlimitedf liability |
Owners are well-diversified | Owners have one primary asset |
Professional management | Owner management |
Company has infinite life | Typical company life of one generation |
Liquid securities efficiently traded | Illiquid securities inefficiently traded |
Profit maximization as goal | Personal wealth creation as goal |
Many underlying assumptions between corporate and private markets theory are different and at odds with each other. Several characteristics are particularly noteworthy:
Differing assumptions underlying corporate finance ultimately limit the utility of these theories to the private markets.
Exhibit 5 compares the application of a number of corporate finance theories to the private capital markets. Since both theories emanate from the same broader economic theories, they share many similarities.8 For instance, private capital providers use the tenets of portfolio theory to manage their portfolios and diversify risk. Conversely, portfolio theory does not uniformly explain behavior in the private capital markets. For example, private owners can not use portfolio theory to diversify their ownership risk because they have nearly all of their wealth tied to one asset.
Exhibit 5: Application of Corporate Finance Theory to the Private Capital Markets
Corporate Finance Theory | Application to the Private Capital Markets |
Net Present Value | Theoretically correct for all firms. Used primarily by public companies. Less than 10% of private companies use NPV to make investment decisions. |
Capital Asset Pricing Theory | Measuring risk and return is a core concept for all markets. The use of beta and other assumptions minimize the utility of the capital asset pricing model for private companies. |
Efficient Market Theory | Applies to both private and public markets. Private capital markets are much less efficient than public markets. |
Portfolio Theory | Used to manage a collection of risky assets. Requires diversification of assets to minimize portfolio risk, which is impossible for a private ownermanager. Portfolio theory is widely used by private capital providers to manage risk and return. |
Option Pricing Theory | Options theory is primarily used for corporate finance. Since private companies do not trade on an exchange, volatility, the degree to which stock price changes exceed their historical average, cannot be measured to support the theory. Used by private firms to assess business options, including stock options, lease options and buy/sell provisions. A version of options theory helps explain the valuation of transfer alternatives faced by private owners. |
Agency Theory | Agency theory explains how to best organize relationships in which one party determines the work, which another party undertakes. Strong management adds to the value of a private firm. Issues exist even for owner-managed private firms. Authorities in the private capital markets can be viewed as agents that provide constraints and rules to the parties. |
Corporate finance theory was developed in the 1960’s to explain large companies in the public capital markets. Economists who originally developed these tools never intended for them to be used to predict other markets’ behavior. Certain corporate finance theories, such as net present value, the capital asset pricing theory and efficient market theory, either are not used by owners of private companies or do not apply to the private markets. Applying these theories in the private market is like utilizing the wrong tools in a tool box. Corporate finance tools were specifically designed to “work on” public market mechanisms.
All capital markets are comprised of commercial activity where motivated parties undertake an exchange because each expects to gain from the exchange. Markets contain mechanisms, or organized sets of activities, which enable participants to exchange interest in, or invest in, companies. In a free market participants have the ability to meet and exchange something for an agreed upon price.
Exhibit 6 depicts several market mechanisms as gears in a market that is greased by information and liquidity.
Exhibit 6: Mechanisms that Structure Markets
The following describes the structure of capital markets, with particular attention given to the comparison of public and private markets.
Information
The role of information is central in both public and private capital markets. Availability, accuracy and access to information lubricate all market mechanisms. Information availability in public markets renders them more efficient. Therefore, in theory, they are less likely to produce deals where one party takes advantage of another because of asymmetrical information. It takes government regulation and enforcement to insure that public information is accurate and available to all.
Availability, accuracy and access to information are significantly different in the private markets. Financial statements are the basic building blocks of information. Most private companies lack audited financial statements and are less likely to prepare their financial statements in compliance with Generally Accepted Accounting Principles. Even that lesser quality information is not made publicly available. This absence of real time, readily available information is a major difference between the markets.
Liquidity
Liquidity is the central value proposition of any market. Liquidity refers to the amount of capital in a market and the flow of that capital internally, as well as into and out of the market. Liquidity is capital in motion and is a necessary lubricant for markets to work because it allows movement from one asset class to another.
Markets are described as more or less liquid. For example, real estate and privately held businesses are typically illiquid investments, while investments in publicly held businesses are considered liquid. The public markets largely transfer fractional interests in a company. Since there is no market to sell private minority interests, most private transfers involve enterprise sales. An enterprise transfer of a private company can easily take a full year, whereas public enterprise sales normally require half that time. Investors in private companies factor a liquidity premium in their return expectations recognizing that these investments are not easily exited.
Market structure is comprised of several mechanisms, among them are:
Market mechanisms provide a structured way to understand complex markets. These mechanisms are the activities or gears that enable a market to operate. Synchronization is possible because each mechanism contains elements of other mechanisms, all operate in a similar information environment and all mechanisms tend toward equilibrium.
Market mechanisms operate in an environment lubricated with information and liquidity and tend toward equilibrium; such is the case of allocating scarce resources.
Allocation
Allocation is the market mechanism of rationing resources. Because resources are finite, markets allocate money, resources, effort, authority, and cooperation as well as tangible and intangible assets. Allocation decisions may be arrived at using a variety of criteria. For example, a first-come, first-serve process benefits the fleet of foot, while a political process allocates benefits based on the ability to manipulate that process.
Resources allocation in the public markets is relatively efficient as demonstrated by both pricing and access to capital by public companies and investors. This is a distinct contrast with the relative inefficiency found in the private capital markets.9
Regulation
Regulation refers to attempts to bring the market under the control of an authority. Regulation is provided by a number of sources, including government and competition.
Government regulation is a pervasive type of regulation, usually expressed as restrictions on behavior. Government regulation provides adjudication of disputes, as well as rules for eligibility and participation. Governments may attempt to control all elements of the market but in a free market system governmental control itself operates under restrictions thereby introducing competing authorities. Public companies are exposed to more extensive governmental regulation than are private companies.
Markets are also regulated through a severe discipline imposed by competition. Firms are not free to raise prices without facing economic consequences. Nor can a company pay its employees whatever it wants. Competition forces efficiency, and ultimately causes supply and demand to balance. Competition regulates the market.
Intermediation
Specialization creates a need for intermediaries to serve as agents of exchange. Paradoxically, specialization leads to increased efficiency based on developing expertise in disparate areas; while simultaneously leading to inefficiency as these areas become increasingly isolated without a controlling authority. Specialization creates the need for information and trading expertise. Intermediaries act as infomediaries where information opacity exists.
Intermediaries add efficiency to a market in several ways. First, they provide a communication system between parties. Second, they work to establish prices that often serve as the starting point in exchange discussions. Finally, they might act as market makers by actually participating in the market as sellers or buyers in order to create a liquid market.
The public transfer market functions with agents and market makers. Investment bankers are agents who advise on public enterprise transfers. Market makers are firms that stand ready to buy and sell a particular stock on a regular and continuous basis at a publicly quoted price. Public agents and market makers provide liquidity and efficiency to the public market. The private transfer market has agents, such as business brokers, M&A intermediaries and private investment bankers. But, strictly speaking there are no private market makers who perform all the functions of market makers in the public market.
Exchange
Market participants in a supply and demand economy are free to exchange for an agreed price. Supply and demand in a market are affected by a host of factors. Shifts in supply or demand cause price increases and decreases. Changes in customer preferences or the cost of money may alter demand. Equilibrium is reached at the point where the greatest numbers of consumers and producers are satisfied.
Exchange, taken as a noun, is an institutionalizing mechanism. Institutionalized exchanges take many forms, including business-to-business, business to consumer, intermediated exchanges and direct exchanges. The nature of the exchange mechanism is the most obvious difference between the public and private markets. There is no single place or entity where an owner or investor might exchange an interest in a private company.
Comparison of the Markets
These market mechanisms are useful in explaining the structure of the private capital markets. The private capital markets are a complex interacting network of discrete exchanges rather than a unified structure. They are quite different from the public markets. For example, institutionalization in the public markets is developed beyond the private markets. In the public market the players are licensed, highly regulated, larger in size and tend to offer a wide range of financial services. In the private markets there are a host of smaller transfer players who provide discrete services. Their services are largely unregulated; however, the SEC and various state authorities provide some regulation.
Exhibit 7: Comparison of the Capital Markets
Market Mechanism | The Public Markets Enjoy: | The Private Markets Exhibit: |
Information | Symmetrical information Transparent information on the subject |
Asymmetrical information Opaque information on the subject |
Liquidity | Transfers of mainly minority interests Instant trading |
Transfers of mainly enterprise interests Long-Term planned exits |
Allocation | Efficient allocation | Fairly inefficient allocation |
Regulation | A regulated market | A mainly non-regulated market |
Intermediation | An industry of agents and market makers | A segmented industry of agents |
Exchange | Continuous pricing | Point in time pricing |
By describing the public markets in terms that apply to all markets they can be compared and contrasted with the private capital markets. It is easy to conclude that the private markets are less mature than the public markets, or that they are emerging markets. And there is certainly a measure of truth in those observations. But there is more to it than that. The private markets are driven by a wide variety of unique motives and the markets have developed mechanisms enabling those unique objectives to be accomplished. In fact, one could argue that the private markets are more sophisticated in that they provide a vast array valuation approaches, capitalization points and transfer mechanisms.
The private capital markets are understandable in terms that apply to all markets. They are a collection of mechanisms, located a free market system, and as such there is no authority controlling the overall structure and function of the market. Rather there are multiple authorities, with various levels of influence and control, operating in certain areas of the market.
The structure of the public and private markets is different. Market mechanisms adapt to meet the needs of the participants in each market. To ignore these structural differences, or to attempt to equalize the markets with a mathematical plug figure, is a mistake in judgment.
Ultimately, the differences between the public and private markets manifest in the pricing of the securities. Since there is no market for private minority interests, any comparison to the public market must be made on an enterprise basis.
There is a substantial difference between the selling process used for enterprise sales of public and lower end, middle market private businesses. Since there is no active market for a private company’s shares, pricing is set by those buyers aware of the situation. This lack of marketability depresses a private company’s stock in two ways. First, investment bankers typically employ a private auction selling process, which limits the number of buyers, and, due to confidentiality issues, probably prohibits competitive bids. Second, the lack of a ready market allows buyers to create a market price for the private shares. Most buyers reduce their risk by setting a low price for the stock.
Public companies draw more attention than private firms when they are for sale. Controlling interests in public companies transfer at substantial premiums over their normal trading ranges because of public auction pricing. Studies by Mergerstat Review, a publication that measures control premiums, show that the average control premium paid in the past ten years was in the 35-45 percent range.10 The public auction process invites the universe of potential buyers, including competitors and hostile takeovers players into the auction.
Exhibit 8 compares public takeover Price/Earnings ratios to private EBIT multiples for a sevenyear period.11 Many people believe public securities pricing determines, or influences, private stock prices. Every year thousands of business appraisers reach into various databases and apply public P/E ratios to derive private values. Also, many private owners read the Wall Street Journal and extrapolate values for their firms from public pricing multiples. These actions presume the two capital markets are related. But is there a correlation between public and private acquisition multiples?
Exhibit 8: Public vs. Private Acquisition Multiples
Year | Median Public Price/Earnings |
Median EBIT Multiple12 |
1996 | 21.7 | 6.0 |
1997 | 25.0 | 5.3 |
1998 | 24.0 | 5.5 |
1999 | 21.7 | 7.4 |
2000 | 18.0 | 6.7 |
2001 | 16.7 | 5.5 |
2002 | 19.7 | 4.8 |
Correlation Coefficient | 0 |
Judging by the table, no correlation is apparent.
To determine a statistical relation, test the data points. A correlation coefficient of “1” indicates a perfect relationship exists, whereas a coefficient of “0” means the variables are unrelated. The correlation coefficient for the public and private acquisition multiples is approximately “0”. In fact, no correlation exists between the public data and other transaction categories ($3-10MM, $10-20MM or $50-100MM).
This lack of correlation is further indication regarding the danger of using public securities data as a surrogate or guide to private stock valuation. If the public transfer market does not drive private pricing, what does? A primary driver of private stock prices is private investor return expectations.
Private Investor Return Expectations
The relationship between private investor return expectations and valuation is straightforward. The greater the perceived risk, the greater the return expected by investors to compensate for this risk. The discount rate is the expected rate of return required to attract capital to an investment, taking into account the rate of return available from other investments of comparable risk. Another way of looking at this risk/return relationship is through using a discount rate as determined by the market for capital.
Calculating the reciprocal of the selling multiples is a shorthand method for determining the discount rate. The private acquisition multiples in the table range between a multiple of 4.8 and 7.4, a narrow multiple range of only 2.6 times earnings. Expressed as a reciprocal, this corresponds to roughly a 14% to 21% discount rate or private investor return expectation (14-21% equals the reciprocal of 7.4 and 4.8, respectively). This return expectation can be tested. Assume a buyer employs a standard capital structure in an acquisition. Thus, 30% of the capital is equity, which carries a 30% return expectation, while 70% of the capital is in debt, which costs about 9%. The implied discount rate in this capital structure is about 15%, within the total return range cited above. Thus, while further study is needed in this area, at least there is a correlation between private investor return expectations and pricing in the table.
Capital Market Lines
Capital markets are segmented by a number of factors, including how participants in the segment view risk and return. Differentiating segments via risk and return is fundamentally important because measuring and managing risk and return is the basis for asset valuation. This means that participants in each segment would value the same asset differently, because they use the concepts of risk and return parochially. It also means that each segment’s capital market line is unique.
A capital market line (CML) is a graphic representation of the expected returns to the capital providers of all institutional capital offerings in a market. Exhibit 9 shows the capital market lines for public and private capital markets.
Exhibit 9: Capital Market Lines
The public company capital markets are fairly efficient. Since security pricing and risk/return are more nearly in alignment, access to capital is predictable. By either of these measures the public market are relatively efficient. Typically pricing differences between public capital alternatives are measured in basis points (1/100 of a percent) rather than percentage points.
The capital asset pricing model determines the Public CML. As expected, the riskier the capital type, the higher the return expectation. For example, public equity holders require returns of 12% or so, but debt holders require less than a 5% return. The Line is viewed as the expected returns on multiple portfolios of investments, as opposed to returns on single securities.
The Private CML describes rates of return required by private investors. This line is empirically based on observations in the market place. There is no widely accepted predictive private capital model, such as the capital asset pricing model, used to determine the risk/return equilibrium of private portfolios of securities. The Private CML is represented by a dashed line to reflect less efficiency in market pricing than the Public market. Expected return differences for capital types are often expressed by percentage point differences, as opposed to basis point differences in the Public CML.
There are several noteworthy things about this chart. First, the Private capital market line is substantially steeper than the Public line. Investors perceive substantially more risk in the private markets and require commensurate returns. Second, if the two markets enjoyed the same level of efficiency, the lines would run parallel to each other separated only by liquidity differences. Finally, capital access is less predictable in the private markets. There is far less institutional support for creating a capital structure in the private markets.
The temptation to use readily available public information to value private companies is strong. It should be noted that within the private capital markets, only academics and business appraisers use the public guideline approach. Other parties in the private capital markets – business owners, lenders, investors, estate planners, etc. – rely on valuation methods that are specifically useful to making decisions in their markets.
Why don’t parties in the private capital markets employ public information in their decision-making process? Because these parties have real money in the markets; valuation is not notional or make-believe to them. Making proper financing and investment decisions requires using theories and methods that are appropriate to the subject’s market.
What are the ramifications to those who borrow theories and ideas from another market? Exhibit 10 describes a number of ramifications of using public information or theories to solve private finance problems.
Exhibit 10: Ramifications of Using Public Information to Solve Private Market Problems
Public Market Given | Ramification in the Private Markets |
Public market stocks trade as minority interests. | There is no market for private minority stock interests. Private investors must have control to determine an exit. |
Public market offers instantaneous trading of minority interests. | Holding period for private stocks is 5-7 years, on an enterprise basis. Private investors must take a very long view toward the investment. |
Public managers can finance projects at the company’s marginal cost of capital. | Most private companies can not access needed capital at any cost. This severely limits a private manager’s ability to plan the growth of the business. |
Public market offers instant pricing of securities. Thus, the perspectives of all investors is reflected in a market price. | Private stocks must be valued at a point in time. This causes a private company to have dozens of correct values at any time, because “value to whom” must be answered for each appraisal purpose. |
Public risk is ascertainable via predictive models such as the CAPM. | No predictive models currently exist to accurately derive the risk of private ownership. Risk, therefore, is empirically observed via acquisition multiples and expected returns of private capital providers. Private cost of equity is often an unknown. |
Judging by the ramifications described in Exhibit 10, it is little wonder that private capital markets players do not heed the advice of those who propose the use of public information to solve private problems. Market players, especially owner-managers, know that what works in the public markets does not necessarily work in the private markets.
But are ‘economic bridges,’ such as lack of marketability discounts or control premiums, helpful in converting public data to private usage? In other words, can public information be contorted in ways that are then useful to private decision-makers? The answer is no. This paper shows that the public markets have specific theories that explain public investor behavior; that these public investors have unique risk and return expectations; that the structure of the public markets are unique; and that access to, and cost of, capital is unique to public markets. It is both surprising and alarming that appraisers are choosing to ignore all of this substantiation and instead treat the public and private markets as substitutes. Or, equally as bad but more often the case, appraisers use quick and easy mathematical adjustments to equalize the markets.
A number of factors indicate that using public data to derive private values is inappropriate. A review of the principle of substitution suggests that public and private markets are not substitutes. Next, the behavior of market players is sufficiently different from market to market. To accurately predict market behavior, capital market theories must be tailored to a specific market. Further, the structure of each market is also unique. Market mechanisms, which provide structure to a market, move differently in public and private markets. Finally, investors within a market have specific return expectations, which are not commensurate with other markets.
The foregoing leaves us with one conclusion: It is a mistake to borrow theories, structure, and expected returns from one market to make financing and investment decisions in another market.
Orginially published Spring 2005 by BAP. Reprinted with permission from Rob Slee, investment banker and president of Robertson Foley, and author of the book Private Capital Markets (published by John Wiley & Sons).
Endnotes
1. Ray Miles, “Where to Find Transaction Data,” Institute of Business Appraisers, 1996, www.goiba.org.
2. Stocks, Bonds, Bills and Inflation 1999 Yearbook, Ibbotson Associates, 2000.
3. Shannon P. Pratt, Robert F. Reilly, and Robert R. Schweihs, Valuing a Business: The Analysis and Appraisal of Closely Held Companies, 4th. Ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill), p. 408.
4. Stocks, Bonds, Bills and Inflation 1999 Yearbook, Ibbotson Associates, 2000.
5. John D. Emory, “The Value of Marketability as Illustrated in Initial Public Offerings of Common Stock”, Business Valuation News, December 1995.
6. See the liquidity hierarchy in: Simpson, “A Minority Interest and Marketability Discount: A perspective,” 10 Business Valuation Review 13 (March 1991).
7. Robert T. Slee, Private Capital Markets: Valuation, Capitalization, and Transfer of Private Business Interests (Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons), 2004.
8. Ibid., See the Foreword.
9. Ibid., Chapter 15.
10. Mergerstat Review 2003 (Los Angeles: Mergerstat, 2003), p. 24.
11. Ibid., p. 25.
12. Taken from the annual International Network of M&A Partners (IMAP) annual surveys, “$20MM-50MM” category, www.imap.com
What is market value? When referencing the “market value” of a business, the actual definition of market value is usually left out of the conversation. Market value, it’s assumed, is simply the amount a hypothetical buyer and seller would be willing to pay/take for a particular business.
The Internal Revenue Service uses a term called “fair market value” and defines it as such:
The fair market value is the price at which the property would change hands between a willing buyer and a willing seller, neither being under any compulsion to buy or to sell and both having reasonable knowledge of relevant facts.
The International Glossary of Business Valuation Terms has a similar definition of fair market value:
Fair market value is the price, expressed in terms of cash equivalents, at which property would change hands between a hypothetical willing and able buyer and a hypothetical willing and able seller, acting at arms length in an open and unrestricted market, when neither is under compulsion to buy or sell and when both have reasonable knowledge of the relevant facts.
Many people use these definitions of fair market value interchangeably with market value.
However, neither definition takes into account the fact that operating businesses are rarely sold for 100% cash. The overwhelming majority of sales are a combination of cash and non-cash compensation, usually in the form of debt instruments (and sometimes equity in the case of larger transactions). Determining a “cash equivalent” for subordinated debt and restricted equity is very challenging….some would say impossible since there are no comparable sales. There are insufficient 100% cash sales of similar businesses, nor are there sufficient sales of restricted stock or subordinated debt in privately-held companies to utilize as a comparison.
It makes far more sense to determine a market price in the context of market terms and conditions in similar business sale transactions. This is more certainly more useful to the reader.
For example, if a business is estimated to be worth $200,000 with $100,000 paid in cash at closing, and the remaining $100,000 as a promissory note, does it really make sense to attempt to discount the note, and present this discounted “cash equivalent” number to the client/owner. If the client/owner reads that his business is worth $180,000 (with the $100,000 note discounted to $80,000), and relies on this information, he or she is going to have a very unrealistic idea of what he or she can expect in a real-world sale scenario. It would be much better for the client/owner (not to mention more accurate) to present the estimated market value of the business at $200,000 under normal terms of 50% in cash and 50% as a promissory note.
The Appraisal Standards Board through their publication, Uniform Standards Professional Appraisal Practice (USPAP) gives a general definition of market value as:
…a type of value, stated as an opinion, that presumes the transfer of a property (i.e., a right of ownership or a bundle of such rights), as of a certain date, under specific conditions set forth in the definition of the term identified by the appraiser as applicable in an appraisal.
However, USPAP stresses that the appraiser must make the final, specific definition of market value, stating:
Appraisers are cautioned to identify the exact definition of market value, and its authority, applicable in each appraisal completed for the purpose of market value.
Consequently we define the market value of a privately-held business enterprise as follows:
Market value is the estimated price, terms and conditions at which a privately-held business would sell under normal selling conditions, including an arms-length, non-distress, and appropriately marketed sale of the business.
What is a Rule of Thumb?
At some point, every business owner has seen or heard of a quick and dirty way to value their business…a rule of thumb. Sometimes they read about it in a magazine or trade journal. Others have heard it from their accountant. Some are quite simple…others more complex…but never so much so that the owner can’t take a napkin and about 30 seconds to figure it out.
So, before we get too far into the topic, just what are “rules of thumb”? In general, a rule of thumb is a quick, simple and non-precise way to evaluate or measure something. Supposedly, the term originated with carpenters and wood workers who would use the width of their thumbs as a quick measurement of one inch rather than stopping their work to hunt for a ruler. We have all heard rules of thumb in many aspects of our personal and professional lives. In driver’s ed (or traffic school), we’ve heard the rule of thumb…stay one car length back for every 10 miles per hour of speed. A pinch of salt is certainly more convenient than using a measuring spoon. The ‘Rule of 72’ measures how long (in years) it takes for a sum of money to double at a particular interest rate. Divide 72 by 8 and you get 9. So at 8% interest, it will take 9 years to double your money….approximately. Each of these rules of thumb are easy to use and remember…and accurate enough to do the job.
Using Rules of Thumb to Value Businesses
It makes sense that people want to discover and use rules of thumb. They make things easy, and that’s generally a good thing. So it shouldn’t surprise anyone that rules of thumb have been developed to help people value their businesses…and there are rules of thumb for almost every industry imaginable. In most cases, these rules of thumb utilize sales revenue because this is something that is relatively easy to determine and calculate. So a rule of thumb for valuing a business in a particular industry might be something like…your widget-making business is worth 75% of sales. So, if your annual sales are $1,000,000, this rule of thumb suggests a value of $750,000.
Sounds simple enough. However, ultimately earnings drive value, not revenue. [see article on discretionary earnings] Owners don’t support themselves and their families on revenue…they do it on earnings…what is left over after paying the bills of the business. Sales of $1,000,000 tell us nothing about what is left over…in earnings. Does it make sense to say that a business with sales of $1,000,000 and earnings of $0 would be worth the same as a business in the same industry with sales of $1,000,000 and earnings of $200,000? Of course not. And this is where rules of thumb for business value fall short. Unlike most rules of thumb, like a pinch of salt, or the Rule of 72, which are ‘close enough’ to be useful, rules of thumb for business value can lead to results that aren’t even in the ballpark.
To Use or Not To Use
So why do people still use rules of thumb? Well, it’s fast, easy, and cheap (as in $0). And usually there is no downside because the business owner is just using the rule of thumb for general information, and not actionable information (i.e. relying on it in an actual transaction scenario). The problem is that this “information” can be (and usually is) completely wrong. And even if it is not being used in a transaction or other actionable situation, it can negatively affect long-term planning decisions. As a wise man once said, “it’s better to have no information than wrong information.” If that axiom holds true, then it is better to ditch the rules of thumb and either remain in the dark, or invest in a professional market business appraisal. Just as you wouldn’t trust a bridge built by a guy using his thumb for measurement, you shouldn’t measure the value of a business using rules of thumb.
From time to time we have been asked why people get business appraisals. The most common reason is for tax compliance; usually for gift or estate taxes. Divorce is another common reason, but these are compliance appraisals, mandated by law, and not market-based. If you want to learn about the differences between market and compliance appraisals, you can check out Business Appraisals 101.
Today, however, we will list the top 5 reasons people get a market appraisal.
1) Sale of the Business
The most common reason for a market appraisal is the potential sale of the business. Typically it happens something like this. The business owner is minding his or her own…ahem…business, and then the phone rings. It is a business broker or “finder”, private-equity firm, competitor, or strategic buyer looking to see if the business owner is interested in selling. The owner is caught off guard, and reacts by hiring an appraiser to get an idea of a price the buyer might be willing to pay, before taking the conversation further. Less frequently, the business owner considers selling at some point in the near future, and hires a business appraiser to find out what his/her business is worth BEFORE actually deciding to sell. This is a more proactive approach, and while commendable, is considerably less common.
2) Partnership Buyouts (with or without Buy/Sell Agreements)
Partners go into business with excitement, aligned interests, and the best of intentions. However, disputes can arise, or interests simply diverge. Often, a health issue with one partner can affect the viability of the working partnership. In most cases, Buy/Sell Agreements are put in place at the beginning of the partnership. These are legally-binding agreements between the partners to decide how a business is to be bought and sold in a fair and equitable way between the partners, avoiding costly litigation. Most Buy/Sell Agreements stipulate the hiring of a business appraiser to establish the market value of the business. Some mandate that each partner hires their own business appraiser, and if the resulting values are close, they are averaged together. If not, a third appraiser is brought in to “break the tie.” With or without a Buy/Sell Agreement in place, a business appraisal is a critical step in ending the partnership without ending the business.
3) Buying a Business
Buying a business is probably the most important financial decision a person will make in their lifetime. Getting a business appraisal can put the buyer’s mind at ease, if the appraisal confirms they are buying the business at a fair price. It also can help keep a buyer from overpaying. Buyers who are smart enough to know what they don’t know, are typically more likely to seek out professional advice.
4) Retirement Planning
Retirement planning has become ever more popular over the years as the Baby Boom generation reaches retirement age. As people live longer and fuller lives, it has become apparent to Boomers and their retirement advisers that, unlike their parents’ generation, they’ll need their money to last decades after retirement. A core component of retirement planning is a full assessment of all assets, including privately-held businesses. Without an objective appraisal of a business asset, a retirement plan is all but useless.
5) Succession Planning
This is similar to retirement planning, except that a family member has been identified, and hopefully groomed, to take over the family business. Often, rather than gifting the business, the owner sells the business to the next generation at a fair price, but with favorable terms to the buyer (think little or no money down, and a long-term note). This provides the seller retirement income, while providing the buyer with financing and possible tax advantages, depending on the sale structure.
All of these reasons for a market appraisal have one thing in common…a transition of ownership. As the wave of Baby Boomers continue to retire in greater numbers over the coming decade, expect more small business transfers…and more market appraisals.
Note: This article applies to market appraisals only. If you are unfamiliar with the difference between market and compliance appraisals, please read this first.
When it comes to business appraisals, most people don’t know what they don’t know. That is, they really don’t know what questions to ask. This site was created, not just to answer questions about business appraisals, but to help business owners, and their advisers, ask the right questions.
So, when you want to hire a business appraiser to perform a market appraisal, make sure you ask these 2 key questions:
1) Will you use private company market data to appraise the business?
Beware the answer of “I consider the market approach”, because many business appraisers “consider” but never (or rarely) actually use the market approach in coming to their conclusion of value. Also, make sure they are using private company market data, and not public company market data. Strange as it may sound, many appraisers use public company data (e.g. stock market data) to value private companies. Can you imagine using Wal-Mart to value the corner general store? Or Google to value a small online business? Unfortunately, this happens all too often.
2) How many appraisals have you performed?
Beware when someone wants to quote the number of years of experience they have. Most CPA’s that perform business appraisals only do one or two a year. So the CPA who boasts 15 years of business appraisal experience may have actually performed only 20 or 30 business appraisals. Experience counts. Make sure you hire a business appraiser with at least 100 appraisals under his or her belt.
If you want a reliable business appraisal, choose an appraiser with strong experience using private company market data.
The first and most important thing one needs to know about business appraisals is that there are two general types: compliance appraisals & market appraisals
Knowing which one you need will save you time, money, and potentially serious headaches down the road.
Compliance Appraisals:
Compliance appraisals are used for complying with some external authority, such as the IRS or a court of law. If you bequeath your business to your son or daughter, you’ll need a business appraisal, because the IRS says so. If you and your spouse divorce, you will need a business appraisal, because the court says so. There are many examples of compliance appraisals, but they are share one common trait…they are required by an external authority to comply with the law.
Market Appraisals:
Market appraisals are used to estimated the market value of a business at a particular time, under a set of assumptions. These assumptions can be varied, and include assumptions about the market of potential buyers. Is this business appraisal assuming a strategic buyer or a financial buyer? A general buyer, or a specific buyer? Market appraisals attempt to estimate the value of a company based on market forces under these assumptions.
Why This Is Important
Since the result of a market appraisal is based on market forces, and the result of a compliance appraisal is based on non-market forces (e.g. legal precedent of the established authority), the results are NEVER the same, and only similar by accident. ONE MUST CHOOSE THE RIGHT TYPE OF APPRAISAL TO GET THE RIGHT ANSWER.
For more about compliance and market appraisals, click here.